Processing math: 100%

Aktuelles

Geopolitical distance and international trade (OeNB Bulletin Q2/25)

Ana Abeliansky, Julian Mayrhuber 1

Recently, the relationship between geopolitical distance and international trade has gained increasing attention, as rising protectionism in large economies is changing trade patterns and is introducing new barriers to economic exchange. While classical trade theories emphasize the importance of economic fundamentals, such as comparative advantage and factor endowments, in shaping trade patterns, emerging research highlights the role of non-economic factors, including political relations. Using a standard gravity model of trade, we estimate the importance of geopolitical distance, as measured by the ideal point distance calculated by Bailey et al. (2017) based on differences in voting patterns at the UN General Assembly. Results suggest that differences in geopolitical alignment are detrimental to trade, especially so in the last decade. This finding is of particular relevance for emerging economies. Moreover, we find that imports by countries which are geopolitically closely aligned with the US appear to be most sensitive to increases in geopolitical distance.

JEL classification: F1, F5, P0

Keywords: international trade, geopolitical distance, globalization

1 Introduction

In an increasingly polarized global landscape, geopolitical fragmentation is reshaping economic exchange and, in particular, international trade dynamics. Rising geopolitical tensions, economic sanctions and shifts in trade alliances have created new uncertainties for global markets, challenging long-established patterns of trade and financial flows (e.g., Aiyar et al., 2023a and Gopinath et al., 2025). Understanding these shifts is crucial, as disruptions in trade can impact economic growth, inflation, exchange rates and financial stability.

Recent research highlights the growing economic consequences of geopolitical fragmentation (e.g., Alvarez et al., 2023; Attinasi et al., 2023; Góes and Bekkers, 2022 and Javorcik et al., 2024). Campos et al. (2023) examine how trade flows are affected by shifting geopolitical alliances, showing that geopolitical fragmentation can lead to significant trade diversion and welfare losses. Fernández-Villaverde et al. (2024) provide empirical evidence on the macroeconomic consequences of fragmentation, particularly its impact on global trade networks and financial stability. Gopinath et al. (2025) further emphasize the role of geopolitical shocks in altering trade patterns, affecting supply chains and influencing global monetary policy responses.

Given the central role of trade (policy) in economic growth, inflationary pressures and exchange rate movements, central banks should take into account these emerging risks to effectively navigate an evolving economic landscape (Frankel and Romer, 1999; Ambrosino et al., 2024; Broda and Romalis, 2011). Along these lines, Attinasi et al. (2024) discuss the challenges central banks face in a fragmenting global trading system, noting that geoeconomic fragmentation increases the complexity and unpredictability of the operating environment. Similarly, Aiyar et al. (2023a) highlight that trade and investment flows are being redirected along geopolitical lines, indicating that there are signs of fragmentation beneath the surface of global trade. Additionally, Qiu et al. (2025) underscore the heightened policy uncertainty and unpredictability stemming from geopolitical tensions, which complicate the economic outlook for central banks. Their study also finds supportive evidence for the negative effect of geopolitical fragmentation on trade values – stemming from effects on prices and quantities.

Building on these findings, this paper investigates the link between geopolitical fragmentation and international trade, exploring how shifting geopolitical relations influence the trade of goods between country pairs. To do so, we use the Base pour l’Analyse du Commerce International (BACI) bilateral trade dataset, which spans from 1995 until 2023. We merge the dataset with standard control variables from the literature (e.g., free trade agreements and common currency for the fixed effects model, or additionally geographical distance and common language for the pooled ordinary least squares regression). Afterward, we combine it with the ideal point distance (IPD) from Bailey et al. (2017) to investigate whether geopolitical differences influence bilateral trade. We then proceed with a heterogeneity analysis across time, type of importer/exporter and geopolitical blocs. Our study improves on past literature by using a wide array of countries, a longer time frame and a broad heterogeneity analysis that has not been done before. In other words, we investigate the relationship between geopolitical differences and international trade across time and also within country groups and blocs. Overall, our findings aim to provide insights into how adverse the effects of geopolitical fragmentation are, and how important it is to build economic resilience in an era of uncertainty. The paper is structured as follows: Section 2 presents the empirical strategy. Section 3 discusses the main findings and assesses their robustness. Finally, section 4 concludes.

2 Empirical strategy

In this section, we introduce the empirical model and describe the data used.

2.1 Empirical model

Most of the large literature investigating the impact of trade barriers on international trade has been based on the theoretically micro-founded model of Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) 2 . The authors propose that bilateral trade can be explained by the economic size of the exporter and importer countries (divided by world GDP), by trade costs needed to move goods across countries (that act as barriers to trade) and by multilateral resistance terms, i.e. the ideal price indices of the exporter and importer countries. The latter essentially allow to control for third-country effects, that is to consider in the analysis the relative importance of a trade barrier compared to trading with alternative trading partners.

Our empirical model for estimation is as follows:

yijt=e(αxijt1 +  βIPDijt1 + γzij+ δit +kjt) ηijt (1)

where yijt is the bilateral import trade share calculated as the value of exports from country i to country j in year t standardized by the value of total imports from country j in year t . Unless otherwise stated, trade shares are import trade shares. We follow other studies such as Eaton et al. (2012), Head and Mayer (2014), Novy (2013) and Carrère et al. (2020) and use trade shares as the dependent variable rather than the value of bilateral trade. 3 Sotelo (2019) and Head and Mayer (2014) propose that the shares diminish the relative importance of large values of trade, since large trade flows are typically directed toward countries with high overall import volumes. Using bilateral trade shares rather than values thus ensures that all countries are weighted equally in the estimation procedure.

Following the standard in the literature, we use a Poisson Pseudo Maximum Likelihood (PPML) regression model to include zeroes in the dependent variable. As Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006) highlight, this regression model should prevent the heteroskedasticity from a log-normalization of the error when we linearize a multiplicative model like that of Anderson and van Wincoop (2003). Sotelo (2019) also shows that using the trade shares in the PPML regression combined with destination country fixed effects is equivalent to a Multinomial Pseudo Maximum Likelihood (MPML) regression described by Gourieroux et al. (1984).

On the right-hand side of equation (1), we include time-variant variables (xijt1) that proxy for time-variant bilateral transport costs such as having a deep trade agreement 4 in place and sharing a common currency. We expect these two variables to enable trade by diminishing the economic costs of trading resulting, e.g., from tariffs or exchange rate uncertainty. Then, we have our main variable of interest, the geopolitical distance  IPDijt1. We expect that geopolitical de-alignment would – if anything – deter trade between countries. Countries usually do not trade as much with “enemies,” as they do with “friends.” The variables xijt1 and  IPDijt1 are lagged by one period to ameliorate endogeneity concerns, mainly stemming from reverse causality.

Furthermore, we include country-pair fixed effects (zij) to absorb any variable measured at the bilateral level which is constant over time and might be correlated with the other covariates. In the specifications without country-pair fixed effects, we include variables that proxy for trade barriers such as the natural logarithm of geographical distance between capitals, having a common border, a common colonial past, a common language and a common religion. While longer distances are expected to diminish trade, since they increase transportation costs, all other variables should increase trade. Our preferred specification is the one that includes country-pair fixed effects, as it also captures all other possible time-invariant factors (at the bilateral level) and we are not specifically interested in one particular variable. Finally, to control for multilateral resistance (and anything that is country- and time-specific), we include the country of origin (i) and time (t) as well as the country of destination (j) and time fixed effects (δit and kjt, respectively). ηijt is the error term, which we assume to be well-behaved. To allow for correlation across time within country pairs, we cluster the standard errors at the country-pair level.

2.2 Data sources and summary statistics

To capture geopolitical (de-)alignment between countries, we rely on the ideal point distance (IPD) from Bailey et al. (2017) that builds on the voting behavior in the United Nations General Assembly (UNGA). The IPD reflects how far apart countries are in terms of their foreign policy positions and it is a widely used measure to study the effects of geopolitical fragmentation (e.g., Abeliansky et al., 2024; Aiyar et al., 2024 and Gopinath et al., 2025). This measure is based on deriving each country’s individual foreign policy position (ideal points) with respect to the US-led liberal order from its UNGA voting behavior. Chart A1 in the annex presents the unilateral ideal points for all the countries of our final sample. Higher ideal points indicate closer alignment with the US-led liberal order, whereas lower values suggest the opposite. Then, the bilateral IPD is calculated as the absolute difference between two countries’ ideal points. Another widely used measure for geopolitical de-alignment is the S-score proposed by Signorino and Ritter (1999), which is simpler to construct than the IPD and reflects how similarly two countries vote in the UNGA. 5 Bailey et al. (2017) argue that the IPD is more suitable than the S-score for time series analysis, as it accounts for shifts in the UNGA agenda. For this reason, we use the IPD as a measure for geopolitical (de-)alignment in our baseline specification. 6

For the bilateral trade shares, we use the BACI dataset from Gaulier and Zignago (2010), which is based on UN COMTRADE data and provides consistent bilateral trade data across countries. It adjusts for discrepancies between reported data from importers and exporters to create a balanced bilateral trade dataset. Furthermore, we also use standard gravity controls (i.e., geographical distance, contiguity, common colonial history, common language and religious proximity) from the CEPII Gravity database (see Conte et al. (2022) for a description of the dataset). Moreover, for information on deep trade agreements, we use the World Bank Deep Trade Agreements database by Hofmann et al. (2017). The variable taken from this dataset covers agreements which support economic integration with respect to trade in goods and services, capital flows and movement of people and ideas (Mattoo et al., 2020). Finally, for data on common currency, we rely on the dataset available from the website of José de Sousa 7 .

Overall, our sample covers annual data ranging from 1995 to 2023 8 . The analysis includes 180 countries, with 34 classified as advanced economies (AEs) and 146 as emerging market and developing economies (EMDEs), following the definition used by the IMF 9 . Table 1 shows the summary statistics for the sample used throughout the analysis. On average, trade shares are around 1% (and this average remains essentially unchanged when zero values are excluded). Moreover, while the between standard deviation of IPD is larger, there is also sufficient within variation, which is important for the analysis at the country-pair level. We also find that in about 18% of the observations, some form of deep trade agreement is in force, while a common currency is shared in around 1% of the sample observations. While trade shares, IPD, common religion and geographical distance are continuous variables, the rest are dichotomous.

Table 1

Summary statistics  
Variable Mean Standard deviation Standard deviation
(between)
Standard deviation
(within)
Number of
observations
Min Max
Trade share 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 890,200 0.0 1.0
IPD(t−1) 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.3 890,200 0.0 5.4
Ln(dist) 8.7 0.8 0.8 0.0 890,200 2.1 9.9
Contig 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.0 890,200 0.0 1.0
Comcol 0.1 0.3 0.3 0.0 890,200 0.0 1.0
Comlang 0.1 0.3 0.4 0.0 890,200 0.0 1.0
Comrelig 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.0 890,200 0.0 1.0
DTA(t−1) 0.2 0.4 0.3 0.2 890,200 0.0 1.0
Comcurr(t−1) 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.1 890,200 0.0 1.0
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Note: IPD(t−1) = ideal point distance, lagged; ln(dist) = geographical distance, logged; contig = common
border; comcol = common colonial past; comlang = common language; DTA(t−1) = deep trade agreement,
lagged; comcurr(t−1) = common currency, lagged.

Since the focus of our study is the relationship between trade and geopolitical distance (IPD), we decided to first provide a graphical illustration of this relationship. Using a binned scatter plot, chart 1 shows that higher geopolitical distance is associated with lower trade shares when controlling for origin and destination country fixed effects. Furthermore, it shows that the link is more negative in 2023 compared to 1995 10 , suggesting that geopolitical alignment has become increasingly important for bilateral trade relations. To analyze the link between trade and geopolitical distance more formally, the next section presents the results of a gravity model analysis.

Chart 1

Here is a chart titled “Trade shares and IPD.” Do you need more accessible information on the visual content of this chart? Please contact the authors directly: ana.abeliansky@oenb.at, julian.mayrhuber@oenb.at.

3 Empirical results

In column (1) of table 2, we try to explain bilateral trade shares by our main variable of interest, i.e. geopolitical distance (IPD). In this specification, we find that IPD is statistically significant at the 1% level. In column (2), we add several control variables which are time-invariant, weakening the statistical significance. The coefficient decreases in size, as would be expected given the correlation of the variables with IPD and with international trade (e.g., two countries that share a common language are also more likely to be geopolitically aligned and trade more). All of the control variables have the expected size, and their sizes are comparable to those in the gravity literature. In column (3), we add two time-variant variables: economic integration agreements and common currency. While we find that the first variable helps explain trade (as expected), the latter does not. Surprisingly, IPD loses its statistical significance, maybe driven by omitted variables. In column (4), we add country-pair fixed effects to control for all time-invariant country-pair heterogeneity, implying that all other bilateral time-invariant variables have to be dropped. In this case, we find that IPD regains its statistical significance at the 1% level. Here, a one-point increase in IPD is associated with a reduction of the share of bilateral trade over the country’s total imports by approximately 7% 11 . 12 Now, the importance of a common currency in promoting trade also gains importance, as economic integration agreements (deep trade agreements – DTAs) also remain as an enabling factor for trade. The estimated coefficient of DTA is now smaller in size compared to column (3), but this is in line with previous results in the literature and expected, since we only consider time variation within country pairs. We conduct the Ramsey RESET test to evaluate the appropriateness of the specifications of the models used for columns (3) and (4). As expected, the test statistics suggest that the model used in column (4) is more adequate.

In table A1 in the annex, we assess the robustness of our main specification, i.e. that of column (4) from table 2. Column (1) is for reference only. In column (2), we use the S-score as an alternative index of geopolitical distance. While the coefficient is not comparable in size, the sign and the statistical significance remain the same. In column (3), we calculate the trade share based on the total exports of the exporting country for each year, rather than based on the imports of each importing country for each year. The results remain qualitatively the same. Moreover, in columns (4) and (5), we exclude both China and the United States from the sample. 13 Here, too, we find that the coefficients remain barely unchanged compared to those of column (1). Finally, column (6) shows that excluding zero values for the trade share variable has little effect on the results and only slightly reduces the coefficients. 14

In terms of sign and size, our results are broadly aligned with the literature. Bosone and Stamato (2024) also find that larger IPD relates to lower trade (measured as total values in their analysis). Gopinath et al. (2025) use the Russian invasion of Ukraine as an event affecting geopolitics and find lower trade after the invasion between different blocs of countries. Our study improves on the past literature by using a wide array of countries, a longer time period and a rich heterogeneity analysis which follows.

Table 2

Trade shares and geopolitical distance (baseline results)  
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Trade share Trade share Trade share Trade share Trade share
IPD(t−1) −0.511*** −0.0516* −0.00217 −0.0672***  
(0.0272) (0.0267) (0.0277) (0.0161)  
Ln(dist)   −1.031*** −0.965***    
  (0.024) (0.0236)    
Contig   0.451*** 0.419***    
  (0.0628) (0.0608)    
Comcol   0.354*** 0.327***    
  (0.0891) (0.0896)    
Comlang   0.534*** 0.512***    
  (0.0617) (0.0617)    
Comrelig   0.429*** 0.396***    
  (0.0772) (0.0792)    
DTA(t−1)     0.389*** 0.0786*** 0.0762***
    (0.0428) (0.0192) (0.0193)
Comcurr(t−1)     0.114 0.159*** 0.122***
    (0.112) (0.0389) (0.0387)
1995-99#IPD(t−1)         −0.0297*
        (0.0177)
2000-04#IPD(t−1)         −0.0400**
        (0.0189)
2005-09#IPD(t−1)         −0.0706***
        (0.019)
2010-14#IPD(t−1)         −0.0830***
        (0.0184)
2015-19#IPD(t−1)         −0.134***
        (0.0192)
2020-23#IPD(t−1)         −0.163***
        (0.0217)
Constant −3.258*** 4.641*** 3.919*** −2.918*** −2.901***
(0.0401) (0.2) (0.199) (0.0194) (0.0199)
Observations 890,200 890,200 890,200 890,200 890,200
Source country-year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Destination country-year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Bilateral FE No No No Yes Yes
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Note: Standard errors clustered at the country-pair level are given in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05,
* p < 0.1; FE = fixed effects; IPD(t−1) = ideal point distance, lagged; ln(dist) = geographical distance, logged;
contig = common border; comcol = common colonial past; comlang = common language; DTA(t−1) = deep
trade agreement, lagged; comcurr(t−1) = common currency, lagged.

3.1 Heterogeneity analysis

Globalization, here measured as the movement of goods across borders, has been described as having different phases, or as evolving with time (see Aiyar et al. 2023a). We want to investigate this further and analyze the relationship between IPD and different time periods. Column (5) of table 2 shows that the importance of IPD as a deterring factor for trade increases over time measured in five-year periods 15 . An alternative approach to investigating the relationship between IPD and time is to interact IPD with year dummies, in a similar approach as before when we interacted IPD with the five-year periods. To make the results more illustrative, we plot the point estimates of the interaction of IPD with each year dummy, as well as with their respective confidence intervals (chart 2). Here, too, we observe overall a rather stable negative and small relationship for the initial years of the sample, but then a descending trend surfaces: The more time elapses, the more geopolitical distance diminishes trade between country pairs. In the annex, chart A2 adds to the results of chart 2 by including the trade shares with respect to the exporter and by replicating the results with trade in levels. As can be seen, both estimates overlap throughout the time frame, supporting the robustness of our results. We posit that the results show that trade could be increasingly used as a punishing mechanism for political differences (see, e.g., Fuchs and Klann (2013) who documented how China reduced imports from countries who received the Dalai Lama as a visitor).

Chart 2

Here is a chart titled “Trade and geopolitical distance (IPD).” Do you need more accessible information on the visual content of this chart? Please contact the authors directly: ana.abeliansky@oenb.at, julian.mayrhuber@oenb.at.

An alternative approach to investigating the heterogeneity analysis is to look at the country groups by origin/destination, by types of country pairs and by country blocs. Chart 3 shows the time-IPD interaction plotted for two different types of economies as exporters – EMDEs and AEs. While we see that for EMDEs the estimated coefficient of IPD is always negative, there is an unexpected positive pattern at the beginning for AEs (which is also found for FDI flows in the complementary analysis by Aiyar et al. (2024)). Subsequently, a non-significant period follows, and finally, a negative period starting from 2015 onward. In these last years, there is an overlap with the estimate for EMDEs. The corollaries for world trade of changing geopolitical distance have become even more negative with the passing of time. We argue that geopolitical distance plays a critical role in shaping trade relationships due to the inherent limitations of complete contracting (Nunn, 2007) and the difficulties associated with contract enforcement. In such contexts, trust becomes a key factor (Guiso et al., 2009), often rooted in perceived friendship or political alignment between countries. If we think of the EMDE countries, these are normally characterized by a weaker institutional environment, and therefore the negative correlation between IPD and trade is stronger (in absolute value) for these countries throughout the sample period. We see the same pattern for destination country groups in chart 4. Why would these geopolitical differences matter more broadly for the economy? Fernández-Villaverde et al. (2024) argue that these are of ultimate importance, since trade disruptions bring inefficiencies in the form of reduced specialization, decreased competition and resource misallocation. The authors reinforce their statement with the argument from Aiyar et al. (2023a) about how difficult it is to replace (imported) goods in the short run (low elasticity of substitution). Our results support those obtained by Fernández-Villaverde et al. (2024) and Hakobyan et al. (2023) who also find that higher fragmentation is especially harmful for emerging economies in terms of their international trade.

Chart 3

Here is a chart titled “Heterogeneity analysis: origin country groups and IPD.” Do you need more accessible information on the visual content of this chart? Please contact the authors directly: ana.abeliansky@oenb.at, julian.mayrhuber@oenb.at.

Chart 4

Here is a chart titled “Heterogeneity analysis: destination country groups and IPD.” Do you need more accessible information on the visual content of this chart? Please contact the authors directly: ana.abeliansky@oenb.at, julian.mayrhuber@oenb.at.

For chart 5, we split the origin and destination countries into four groups based on the AE and EMDE classification. We observe that a higher IPD always deters trade between EMDE countries, which is as expected and aligned with what we also observed in charts 3 and 4. On the contrary, for trade between advanced economies IPD does not seem to really matter. It might therefore prove more interesting to see what happens when we consider trade between different country groups. For trade from AEs to EMDEs, we observe that IPD starts having a negative and statistically significant effect (increasing in absolute value with the passing of time) only after the year 2016 (see top right panel of chart 5). For trade from EMDEs to AEs, this is the case from 2019 onward, with the negative association being stronger (see bottom left panel of chart 5). This period coincided with stock market volatility, which has put higher pressure on emerging economies, with the US-China trade war in 2018, which has increased uncertainty, and with trade tensions and deglobalization trends like Brexit.

Chart 5

Here is a chart titled “Heterogeneity analysis: origin and destination country groups and IPD.” Do you need more accessible information on the visual content of this chart? Please contact the authors directly: ana.abeliansky@oenb.at, julian.mayrhuber@oenb.at.

Finally, we observe the dynamics between IPD and trade across country blocs, based on their geopolitical distance to the US and China, respectively. More precisely, we define the blocs as countries that are positioned within the closest quartile in terms of IPD either to the US or China for every year. The remaining countries are defined as non-aligned countries. 16 First, we look at trade between countries belonging to the same blocs. IPD mostly does not seem to matter for trade within blocs – in fact, belonging to the same bloc seems to act as a “trust mechanism” where small differences do not seem to play a role. Between non-aligned countries, changes in IPD do not seem to change bilateral trade during the beginning and end of our sample period. However, in the middle period, they seem to do – one should also not forget that these were years of increased economic uncertainty due to the financial crisis. For trade within the US bloc, we see that after the financial crisis increases in IPD do deter trade. We postulate that, unlike in the case of the China bloc, belonging to the same bloc does not necessarily provide a “trust mechanism.” While China has a tight relationship with partners in terms of trade, FDI (which are interrelated, see Abeliansky and Martínez-Zarzoso (2019)) and migration, this is not the case for the US. Also, the US is a more closed economy, while China relies more on its internationalization as a growth strategy. Non-aligned countries as importers mostly do not seem to be affected by IPD (see middle column of chart 6). Non-aligned exporters only seem to be influenced by larger IPD when trading with the US bloc (see middle row in chart 6). Interestingly, the negative relationship between trade and IPD between the US and China blocs (China–US; US–China) seems to increase with time, being insignificant at the beginning of the period. Thus, the US bloc seems to be most sensitive to IPD as an importer, while this is the case for the Chinese bloc only when trading with the US plus allies as a counterpart.

Chart 6

Here is a chart titled “Heterogeneity analysis: origin and destination country blocs and IPD.” Do you need more accessible information on the visual content of this chart? Please contact the authors directly: ana.abeliansky@oenb.at, julian.mayrhuber@oenb.at.

4 Conclusion

In this paper, we explore how geopolitical distance is associated with bilateral trade shares. Using a comprehensive dataset in terms of countries and years, we combine standard gravity variables with a measure of geopolitical distance, namely the IPD from Bailey et al. (2017). This measure builds on countries’ voting behavior in the UNGA. Relying on a gravity model estimated with a PPML regression, we find that greater geopolitical distance is linked to significantly lower trade shares. This negative relationship proves to be robust across different model specifications. At the same time, our heterogeneity analysis highlights important differences across time periods, country groups and geopolitical blocs.

The results show that the relationship between geopolitical distance and trade becomes more negative over time, especially in recent years, which were marked by broader geopolitical uncertainty and trade tensions. Furthermore, the negative association between geopolitical distance and trade is particularly present for EMDEs, which might be more vulnerable to geopolitical risks due to weaker institutions. However, in recent years, the negative relationship between trade and geopolitical distance has also become increasingly important for AEs, which is in line with increasing geopolitical tensions and trade conflicts. When looking at trade within the same and between different country groups, we find notable differences. While the relationship is negative but relatively stable for trade between EMDEs, we find no clear evidence for the importance of geopolitical distance for trade between AEs. However, for trade between different country groups (from AEs to EMDEs and vice versa), we find that the relationship between geopolitical distance and trade shares turns negative and significant starting in around 2016.

In our bloc analysis, we define country blocs based on their geopolitical distance to the US or China. We find that IPD has little effect on trade between countries belonging to the same blocs (except for trade within the US bloc), meaning that changes in geopolitical distance do not seem to matter much in these cases. However, for trade between different blocs, especially involving the US bloc, the negative effect of geopolitical distance becomes stronger over time. This indicates that geopolitical distance between major blocs (close to China or the US) has become a growing barrier to trade over the past years.

Overall, our results point to the growing role of geopolitical distance in shaping global trade flows. It will be left for future research (when more data become available) to show the point estimates for 2024 and 2025, since at the time of writing of this article the world is experiencing changes in the geopolitical order as well as rising protectionism. As political tensions increase, understanding these dynamics becomes increasingly important for tracking changes in trade patterns and assessing potential economic vulnerabilities.

5 References

Abeliansky, A. L., C. A. Belabed and J. Mayrhuber. 2024. Enjoy the silence? (De)globalization and cross-border investment – a gravity approach. In: OeNB Bulletin Q2/24.

Abeliansky, A. L. and I. Martínez-Zarzoso. 2019. The relationship between the Chinese ‘going out’ strategy and international trade. In: Economics 13(1), 20190021.

Aiyar, S., A. Ilyina et al. 2023a. Geoeconomic fragmentation and the future of multilateralism. Staff Discussion Note SDN/2023/001. International Monetary Fund.

Aiyar, S., A., Presbitero and M. Ruta (eds.). 2023b. Geoeconomic fragmentation: the economic risks from a fractured world economy. CEPR Press.

Aiyar, S., D. Malacrino and A. F. Presbitero. 2024. Investing in friends: The role of geopolitical alignment in FDI flows. In: European Journal of Political Economy 83. June 24. 102508.

Alvarez, J., A. Sollaci, C. Maggi, M. Stuermer, M. B. Andaloussi and P. Topalova. 2023. Geoeconomic fragmentation and commodity markets (No. 2023/201). International Monetary Fund.

Ambrosino, L., J. Chan and S. Tenreyro (2024). Trade Fragmentation, Inflationary Pressures and Monetary Policy. Bank for International Settlements, Monetary and Economic Department.

Anderson, J. E. 1979. A theoretical foundation for the gravity equation. In: The American Economic Review 69(1), 106–116.

Anderson, J. E. and E. van Wincoop. 2003. Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. In: American Economic Review 93(1). 170–192.

Attinasi, M. G., L. Boeckelmann and B. Meunier. 2023. The economic costs of supply chain decoupling. The World Economy.

Attinasi, M. G. et al. 2024. Navigating a Fragmenting Global Trading System: Insights for Central Banks. ECB Occasional Paper No. 2024/365.

Bailey, M. A., A. Strezhnev and E. Voeten. 2017. Estimating dyadic state preferences from UN voting data. In: Journal of Conflict Resolution 61(2). 430–456.

Baier, S., J. H. Bergstrand and M. Feng. 2014 Economic integration agreements and the margins of international trade. In: Journal of International Economics 93(2). 339–350.

Bergstrand, J. H. 1985. The gravity equation in international trade: some microeconomic foundations and empirical evidence. The review of economics and statistics. 474–481.

Bergstrand, J. H. 1989. The generalized gravity equation, monopolistic competition, and the factor-proportions theory in international trade. The review of economics and statistics. 143–153.

Bosone, C. and G. Stamato. 2024. Beyond borders: How geopolitics is changing trade. European Central Bank Working Paper Series.

Broda, C. and J. Romalis. (2011). Identifying the relationship between trade and exchange rate volatility. In: Commodity prices and markets. University of Chicago Press. 79–110.

Campos, R. G., J. Estefania-Flores, D. Furceri, and J. Timini. 2023. Geopolitical fragmentation and trade. In: Journal of Comparative Economics 51(4). 1289–1315.

Carrère, C., M. Mrázová and J. Neary. 2020. Gravity without Apology: The Science of Elasticities, Distance, and Trade. CESifo Working Paper No. 8160, Center for Economic Studies and ifo Institute (CESifo), Munich.

Conte, M., P. Cotterlaz and T. Mayer. 2022. The CEPII gravity database.

Eaton, J., S. S. Kortum and S. Sotelo. 2012. International trade: Linking micro and macro (No. w17864). National bureau of economic research.

Frankel, J. and D. Romer. 1999. Does trade cause growth? In: American Economic Review 89(3). 379–399.

Fuchs, A. and N. H. Klann. 2013. Paying a visit: The Dalai Lama effect on international trade. In: Journal of International Economics 91(1). 164–177.

Gaulier, G. and S. Zignago. 2010. BACI: International Trade Database at the Product-Level. The 1994–2007 Version. CEPII Working Paper No. 2010-23.

Góes, C. and E. Bekkers. 2022. The impact of geopolitical conflicts on trade, growth and innovation. WTO Working Paper ERSD-2022-09. World Trade Organization.

Gopinath, G., P. O. Gourinchas, A. F. Presbitero and P. Topalova. 2025. Changing global linkages: A new Cold War? In: Journal of International Economics 153, 104042.

Gourieroux, C., A. Monfort and A. Trognon. 1984. Pseudo maximum likelihood methods: Theory. In: Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society. 681–700.

Guiso, L., P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales. 2009. Cultural biases in economic exchange? In: The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(3). 1095–1131.

Hakobyan, S., R. Zymek and S. Meleshchuk. 2023. Divided we fall: Differential exposure to geopolitical fragmentation in trade. No. 2023/270. International Monetary Fund.

Head, K. and T. Mayer. 2014. Gravity equations: Workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook. In: Handbook of international economics (Vol. 4). Elsevier. 131–195.

Hummels, D. and P. J. Klenow. 2005. The variety and quality of a nation’s exports. In: American Economic Review 95(3). 704–723.

Hofmann C., A. Osnago and M. Ruta. 2017. Horizontal Depth: A New Database on the Content of Preferential Trade Agreements. Policy Research working paper No. WPS 7981. Washington, D.C: World Bank Group.

Javorcik, B., L. Kitzmueller, H. Schweiger and M. A. Yıldırım. 2024 . Economic costs of friendshoring. In: The World Economy 47(7). 2871–2908.

Larch, M., S. Shikher and Y. Yotov. 2025. Estimating Gravity Equations: Theory Implications, Econometric Developments, and Practical Recommendations (No. 2025001).

Lijphart, A. 1963. The analysis of bloc voting in the General Assembly: A critique and a proposal. In: American Political Science Review 57(4). 902–917.

Mattoo, A., N. Rocha and M. Ruta. 2020. Handbook of deep trade agreements. World Bank Publications.

Novy, D. 2013. International trade without CES: estimating translog gravity. In: Journal of International Economics 89 (2). 271–282.

Nunn, N. 2007. Relationship-specificity, incomplete contracts, and the pattern of trade. In: The quarterly journal of economics 122(2). 569–600.

Qiu, H., D. Xia and J. Yetman. 2025. The role of geopolitics in international trade. BIS Working Paper No 1249.

Santos Silva, J. M. C. and S. Tenreyro. 2006. The log of gravity. In: The Review of Economics and Statistics 88(4). 641–658.

Signorino, C. S. and J. M. Ritter. 1999. Tau-b or not tau-b: Measuring the similarity of foreign policy positions. In: International Studies Quarterly 43(1). 115–144.

Sotelo, S. 2019. Practical aspects of implementing the multinomial PML estimator. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, mimeo.

Tinbergen, J. 1962. Shaping the world economy: suggestions for an international economic policy.

Fernández-Villaverde, J., T. Mineyama and D. Song. 2024. Are we fragmented yet? Measuring geopolitical fragmentation and its causal effect (No. w32638). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Voeten, E., A. Strezhnev and M. Bailey. 2009. United Nations General Assembly Voting Data. Harvard Dataverse. United Nations General Assembly Voting Data - Erik Voeten Dataverse (harvard.edu)

6 Annex

Advanced economies: Andorra, Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Cyprus, Czechia, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Latvia, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Singapore, Slovakia, Slovenia, South Korea, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States.

Emerging market and developing economies: Afghanistan, Albania, Algeria, Angola, Antigua & Barbuda, Argentina, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bahamas, Bahrain, Bangladesh, Barbados, Belarus, Belize, Benin, Bhutan, Bolivia, Bosnia & Herzegovina, Botswana, Brazil, Brunei, Bulgaria, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cambodia, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Chile, China, Colombia, Comoros, Congo (Democratic Republic of the), Congo (Republic of the), Costa Rica, Côte d’Ivoire, Croatia, Cuba, Djibouti, Dominica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Equatorial Guinea, Eswatini, Ethiopia, Fiji, Gabon, Gambia, Georgia, Ghana, Grenada, Guatemala, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Iran, Iraq, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakhstan, Kenya, Kiribati, Kuwait, Kyrgyzstan, Laos, Lebanon, Lesotho, Liberia, Libya, Madagascar, Malawi, Malaysia, Maldives, Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius, Mexico, Micronesia (Federated States of), Moldova, Mongolia, Morocco, Mozambique, Myanmar (Burma), Namibia, Nepal, Nicaragua, Niger, Nigeria, North Korea, North Macedonia, Oman, Pakistan, Panama, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Qatar, Romania, Russia, Rwanda, Samoa, São Tomé & Príncipe, Saudi Arabia, Senegal, Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Solomon Islands, Somalia, South Africa, Sri Lanka, St. Kitts & Nevis, St. Lucia, St. Vincent & Grenadines, Sudan, Suriname, Syria, Tajikistan, Tanzania, Thailand, Togo, Tonga, Trinidad & Tobago, Tunisia, Türkiye, Turkmenistan, Uganda, Ukraine, United Arab Emirates, Uruguay, Uzbekistan, Vanuatu, Venezuela, Vietnam, Yemen, Zambia, Zimbabwe.

Chart A1

Here is a chart titled “Average unilateral ideal points (1995–2023).” Do you need more accessible information on the visual content of this chart? Please contact the authors directly: ana.abeliansky@oenb.at, julian.mayrhuber@oenb.at.

Table A1

Robustness  
  (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
  Trade shares Trade shares Trade shares
(exports)
Trade shares Trade shares Trade shares
IPD(t−1) −0.0672***   −0.0506** −0.0669*** −0.0699*** −0.0614***
(0.0161)   (0.0249) (0.0173) (0.0169) (0.0161)
DTA(t−1) 0.0786*** 0.0791*** −0.0362 0.0973*** 0.0679*** 0.0675***
(0.0192) (0.0193) (0.0291) (0.02) (0.0207) (0.0187)
Comcurr(t−1) 0.159*** 0.151*** 0.106** 0.156*** 0.173*** 0.138***
(0.0389) (0.0387) (0.0414) (0.0404) (0.046) (0.0387)
S-score(t−1)   −0.131***        
  (0.0376)        
Constant −2.918*** −3.065*** −2.821*** −3.033*** −3.061*** −2.907***
(0.0194) (0.0228) (0.0314) (0.0213) (0.0177) (0.0194)
           
Observations 890,200 890,200 890,200 880,070 880,070 648,131
Source country-year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Destination country-year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Bilateral FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Sample Full S-score Export shares Excluding China Excluding USA Excluding zeroes
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Note: Standard errors clustered at the country-pair level are given in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1; FE =
fixed effects; IPD(t−1) = ideal point distance, lagged; DTA(t−1) = deep trade agreement, lagged; comcurr(t−1) = common
currency, lagged; S-score(t−1) = S-score, lagged.

Chart A2

Here is a chart titled “Robustness check: IPD and trade in shares and in levels.” Do you need more accessible information on the visual content of this chart? Please contact the authors directly: ana.abeliansky@oenb.at, julian.mayrhuber@oenb.at.


  1. Oesterreichische Nationalbank, International Economics Section, and . Opinions expressed by the authors of studies do not necessarily reflect the official viewpoint of the OeNB or the Eurosystem. This publication is part of a larger project on (de)globalization, the (De)Globalization Monitor (GloMo), conducted at the OeNB’s International Economics Section. The project comprises analyses of capital flows and cross-border investment (CapMo), trade (TradeMo) and migration (MigMo). Members of the project team are Ana Abeliansky, Christian Alexander Belabed, Julian Mayrhuber, Anna Katharina Raggl and Paul Ramskogler (all OeNB, International Economics Section). The authors would like to thank the GloMo team and Fabio Rumler for helpful comments and valuable suggestions. ↩︎

  2. While Tinbergen (1962) has been cited as a popular reference for the gravity model of trade, it was Anderson (1979) and Bergstrand (1985, 1989) who derived the first theoretical applications, followed by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) who provided a micro-theoretical foundation to the gravity model equation. ↩︎

  3. Following Baier et al. (2014, p. 343), the trade shares can also be understood as the multiplication of the extensive and intensive margin of trade. This also builds on the model of Hummels and Klenow (2005) who originally looked at the margins of trade but at the country level. ↩︎

  4. There are different types of economic integration agreements, with some agreements including further liberalizations and integration dimensions. Since the aim of the paper is not to investigate their differential effect, we consider any agreement in our dataset to be a deep trade agreement, following the naming used in the data sources described in the next section. ↩︎

  5. We obtain the S-score by linearly transforming the Lijphart Index of Agreement (Lijphart, 1963) provided by Voeten et al. (2009). ↩︎

  6. Still, the IPD and the S-score are strongly correlated in our sample (bivariate correlation of 0.85), and our robustness checks confirm that using either measure leads to similar results. ↩︎

  7. Retrieved from http://jdesousa.univ.free.fr/data/cu/cu_faq.htm and further updated. ↩︎

  8. The starting and end year are determined by the availability from the BACI dataset. ↩︎

  9. For a few countries not classified by the IMF, we assigned the classifications manually: Liechtenstein is treated as an AE, while Cuba, Micronesia (Federated States of), and North Korea are treated as EMDEs. A full list of countries is provided in the annex. ↩︎

  10. 1995 is the first and 2023 the last year of the sample. ↩︎

  11. The exact number is calculated as follows: (e0.0672 1)100= 6.5%. ↩︎

  12. A one-point increase in the IPD can be found between 2021 and 2022 for the relationship between Germany and China. ↩︎

  13. We remove them as a robustness check, because they are the largest economies and are of special interest in the recent political economy literature. By excluding them, we want to see whether the results remain the same. ↩︎

  14. Following the developments of the gravity literature, we include internal trade (measured as GDP minus exports) in an auxiliary regression. While the results remain qualitatively the same, given the nature of our research question and the drawbacks of using imprecise internal trade data, we prefer to keep our empirical setup (Larch et al. (2025) also suggest that using internal trade is not always feasible). In addition, we follow Larch et al. (2025) and replicate column (4) of table 2 with the new Stata command ppml_fe_bias (which corrects for potential issues arising as incidental parameter problems in PPML models with more than one fixed effect). We find quantitatively the same results. ↩︎

  15. The last period from 2020 to 2023 only contains four years. Results are not sensitive to the definition of the periods, neither when taking the first period as the baseline of the interactions. ↩︎

  16. For 2023, examples for US bloc countries are Australia, Canada, Israel and most European countries (France, Germany, Italy, etc.). Countries belonging to the China bloc in 2023 are, i.a., Bolivia, Egypt, Mongolia and Vietnam, while in the same year the non-aligned countries consisted, i.a., of Argentina, Brazil, India and Türkiye. ↩︎